Fairvote Canada

735 readers
13 users here now

Matrix Chat


What is This Group is About?

De Quoi Parle ce Groupe?


The unofficial non-partisan Lemmy movement to bring proportional representation to all levels of government in Canada.

🗳️Voters deserve more choice and accountability from all politicians.


Le mouvement non officiel et non partisan de Lemmy visant à introduire la représentation proportionnelle à tous les niveaux de gouvernement au Canada.

🗳️Les électeurs méritent davantage de choix et de responsabilité de la part de tous les politiciens.




Related Communities/Communautés Associées

Resources/Ressources

Official Organizations/Organisations Officielles



Content Moderation Policies

We're looking for more moderators, especially those who are of French and indigenous identities.


Politiques de modération de contenu

Nous recherchons davantage de modérateurs, notamment ceux qui sont d'identité française et autochtone.


founded 1 year ago
MODERATORS
601
50
submitted 4 months ago by Sunshine to c/fairvote
 
 
602
 
 

CIVIX Canada on Bluesky

📢 The results for #StudentVoteON are now in!

🍁 242,407 students cast ballots from 1,839 schools in Ontario ⁠

✔️ Access the preliminary results here: studentvote.ca/results/on2025

Results by Party

Party Seats Seats % Vote %
PC 51 41.13% 24.14%
ONDP 41 33.06% 23.47%
OLP 28 22.58% 23.74%
GPO 3 2.42% 15.55%
Ind. 1 0.81% 2.22%
New Blue Party 0 0.00% 5.66%
Ontario Party 0 0.00% 2.17%
603
604
605
 
 

https://www.fairvote.ca/board-election-2025/

Le Mouvement pour la représentation équitable au Canada est guidé par un conseil d’administration composé de 15 membres bénévoles. Sept administrateurs doivent être élus cette année : les cinq premiers élus auront un mandat de trois ans, le sixième aura un mandat de deux ans, et le septième aura un mandat d’un an.

Dates importantes Description
2025-03-11 Session d’information en ligne pour les candidates et candidats potentiels. Inscrivez-vous ici.
2025-03-14 est la dernière date à laquelle les nouveaux membres doivent s’inscrire pour pouvoir se présenter ou voter. Pour devenir membre, vous devez avoir fait un don de 25 $ au Mouvement pour la représentation équitable au Canada au cours de l’année (ou 5 $ si vous êtes un groupe à faible revenu, un groupe de jeunes ou un groupe en quête d’équité) ou faire un don d’au moins 5 $ par mois. Faites un don ici.
2025-04-14 Date limite pour les nominations. Ces personnes se présentent à l’élection en remplissant ce formulaire.
2025-05-14 Le vote commence.
2025-05-24 Clôture du vote. Annonce des résultats.
2025-06-07 Les résultats des élections sont ratifiés par les membres lors de notre assemblée générale annuelle (par Zoom).
606
 
 

https://www.fairvote.ca/board-election-2025/

Fair Vote Canada is guided by a volunteer Board of 15 Directors. Seven Directors are to be elected this year. Five elected candidates will serve three-year terms. One is to be elected to a two-year term, and one to a one-year term.

Important Dates Description
2025-03-11 Information session for Prospective Candidates. Registration link here.
2025-03-14 is the last date for new members to join in order to be eligible to run or vote. To be a member, you must have donated $25 to Fair Vote Canada over the year (or $5 if you are a low income/youth/equity-seeking group) or donate at least $5 monthly. Donate here.
2025-04-14 deadline for nominations. Candidates may self-nominate by completing this form.
2025-05-14 Voting begins.
2025-05-24 Voting closes. Results announced.
2025-06-07 Election results are ratified by members at our Annual General Meeting (by Zoom).
607
 
 

In these 32 ridings the PC candidate won thanks to vote splitting. Results are as of this morning and may have changed slightly.

Thanks to all spoiler candidates listed below /s

26 spoiler candidates are New Democrats, 11 are Green, and 5 are Liberal. Only one NDP candidate, Natasha Doyle-Merrick, had the decency to step down in Eglinton-Lawrence, but that election was still spoiled by Green candidate Leah Tysoe 😡

First past the post 👎👎👎


York South-Weston: election spoiled by Faisal Hassan (NDP); Daniel Di Giorgio (Liberal) would have won by 7957 votes (25%)

Hamilton Mountain: election spoiled by Kojo Damptey (NDP); Dawn Danko (Liberal) would have won by 8021 votes (21%)

Peterborough-Kawartha: election spoiled by Jen Deck (NDP); Adam Hopkins (Liberal) would have won by 7232 votes (13%)

Sault Ste. Marie: election spoiled by Gurwinder Dusanjh (Liberal); Lisa Vezeau-Allen (NDP) would have won by 2920 votes (10%)

Burlington: election spoiled by Megan Beauchemin (NDP); Andrea Grebenc (Liberal) would have won by 4447 votes (8%)

Hamilton East-Stoney Creek: election spoiled by Zaigham Butt (NDP); Heino Doessing (Liberal) would have won by 2784 votes (7%)

Kitchener South-Hespeler: election spoiled by Jeff Donkersgoed (NDP) and Jessica Riley (Green); Ismail Mohamed (Liberal) would have won by 2653 votes (7%)

Scarborough Centre: election spoiled by Sonali Chakraborti (NDP); Mazhar Shafiq (Liberal) would have won by 2104 votes (7%)

Kitchener-Conestoga: election spoiled by Jodi Szimanski (NDP); Joe Gowing (Liberal) would have won by 2636 votes (6%)

Bruce-Grey-Owen Sound: election spoiled by Joel Loughead (Green) and James Harris (NDP); Selwyn Hicks (Liberal) would have won by 2591 votes (6%)

Wellington-Halton Hills: election spoiled by Bronwynne Wilton (Green) and Simone Kent (NDP); Alex Hilson (Liberal) would have won by 3061 votes (6%)

Bay of Quinte: election spoiled by Amanda Robertson (NDP); David O'Neil (Liberal) would have won by 2629 votes (6%)

Mississauga-Erin Mills: election spoiled by Mubashir Rizvi (NDP); Qasir Dar (Liberal) would have won by 2067 votes (6%)

Thunder Bay-Atikokan: election spoiled by Stephen Margarit (Liberal); Judith Monteith-Farrell (NDP) would have won by 1436 votes (5%)

Willowdale: election spoiled by Boris Ivanov (NDP); Paul Saguil (Liberal) would have won by 1192 votes (4%)

Eglinton-Lawrence: election spoiled by Leah Tysoe (Green); Vince Gasparro (Liberal) would have won by 1223 votes (3%)

Milton: election spoiled by Katherine Cirlincione (NDP) and Susan Doyle (Green); Kristina Tesser Derksen (Liberal) would have won by 993 votes (2%)

Cambridge: election spoiled by Marjorie Knight (NDP); Rob Deutschmann (Liberal) would have won by 999 votes (2%)

Whitby: election spoiled by Jamie Nye (NDP) and Steven Toman (Green); Roger Gordon (Liberal) would have won by 1130 votes (2%)

Mississauga East-Cooksville: election spoiled by Alex Venuto (NDP); Bonnie Crombie (Liberal) would have won by 649 votes (2%)

Perth-Wellington: election spoiled by Jason Davis (NDP) and Ian Morton (Green); Ashley Fox (Liberal) would have won by 674 votes (2%)

Pickering-Uxbridge: election spoiled by Khalid Ahmed (NDP) and Mini Batra (Green); Ibrahim Daniyal (Liberal) would have won by 692 votes (2%)

Brantford-Brant: election spoiled by Ron Fox (Liberal) and Karleigh Csordas (Green); Harvey Bischof (NDP) would have won by 764 votes (1%)

Parry Sound-Muskoka: election spoiled by David Innes (Liberal); Matt Richter (Green) would have won by 451 votes (1%)

Mississauga-Lakeshore: election spoiled by Spencer Ki (NDP); Elizabeth Mendes (Liberal) would have won by 350 votes (1%)

Newmarket-Aurora: election spoiled by Denis Heng (NDP); Chris Ballard (Liberal) would have won by 329 votes (1%)

Mississauga Centre: election spoiled by Waseem Ahmed (NDP); Sumira Malik (Liberal) would have won by 216 votes (1%)

Etobicoke Centre: election spoiled by Giulia Volpe (NDP) and Brian Morris (Green); John Campbell (Liberal) would have won by 258 votes (1%)

Mississauga-Streetsville: election spoiled by Shoaib Khawar (NDP); Jill Promoli (Liberal) would have won by 183 votes

Scarborough-Rouge Park: election spoiled by Hibah Sidat (NDP) and Victoria Jewt (Green); Morris Beckford (Liberal) would have won by 115 votes

Algoma-Manitoulin: election spoiled by Reg Niganobe (Liberal); David Timeriski (NDP) would have won by 94 votes

Oakville: election spoiled by Diane Downey (NDP); Alison Gohel (Liberal) would have won by 2 votes

608
609
17
submitted 4 months ago* (last edited 3 months ago) by AlolanVulpix to c/fairvote
 
 

Preface

I'm writing this on the eve of Ontario's 2025 election. I know that this is unfortunately another election that is not held under a proportional representation (PR) electoral system.

I am just an ordinary Canadian citizen -- I don't consider myself an activist, yet I can recognize an unfair and abusive system.

But now is not the time to let pessimism dissuade us from the democracy we deserve. With Duverger's Law (i.e., in non-PR electoral systems, a trend towards a two-parties), we are running out of time to act. Canada's 2021 effective number of parties is 2.76 - this number will decrease over time, and will eventually end Canadian democracy as we know it today.

I'm not writing this to get donation money (although here is the Fair Vote Canada donation site), but this is just the reality with live with and the future we are fighting for.

Proposed 2025 objective

While I love a good, yeasty, loaf of bread 🍞, [email protected] has 638 subscribers, which is 144.4% more than our 261. I suppose you could say I'm jealous.

Next steps

Before the end of March 2025, please comment on whether:

  • this is a good objective to have
  • if it's not a good objective, what other objectives should we pursue
  • Ideas on how to achieve our objectives

Statistics

Date users/month u/m % of c/Canada mod/u/m posts comments Subscribers subscribers % of c/Canada
2025-02-26 - - - - - 261 -
2025-02-28 785 - - - - - -
2025-03-03 866 11.994% 23.09‱ 205 629 323 3.968%
2025-03-04 942 13.120% 21.23‱ 211 654 342 4.191%
2025-03-05 894 12.556% 22.37‱ 213 665 354 4.317%
2025-03-06 891 11.770% 22.45‱ 218 674 374 4.539%
2025-03-07 904 10.984% 22.12‱ 219 683 377 4.531%
2025-03-08 951 11.149% 21.03‱ 229 694 389 4.587%
2025-03-09 971 11.174% 20.60‱ 232 706 406 4.749%
2025-03-10 1.02k 11.384% 19.61‱ 237 740 421 4.867%
2025-03-11 1.04k 11.441% 19.608‱ 238 750 437 5.017%
2025-03-12 1.05k 11.254% 19.048‱ 239 751 441 5.029%
2025-03-13 1.12K 11.655% 17.857‱ 247 804 442 5.017%
2025-03-14 1.17k 12.037% 17.094‱ 259 828 448 5.062%
2025-03-15 1.19k 12.143% 16.807‱ 270 853 452 5.079%
2025-03-16 1.22k 12.449% 16.393‱ 273 868 459 5.140%
2025-03-17 1.3k 13.333% 15.385‱ 280 907 465 5.196%
2025-03-18 1.33K 13.516% 15.038‱ 291 952 469 5.229%
2025-03-19 1.36k 13.977% 14.706‱ 296 989 471 5.233%
2025-03-20 1.41k 9.78k (u/m Canada) 2 (mods) 310 1.04k 474 9.02k (subs Canada)
2025-03-21 1.48k 10k 2 332 1.04k 479 9.04k
2025-03-22 1.51k 10.3k 2 348 1.1k 481 9.06k
2025-03-23 1.53k 10.4k 2 361 1.13k 485 9.08k
2025-03-24 1.55k 10.4k 2 370 1.18k 490 9.1k
2025-03-25 1.58k 10.5k 2 382 1.22k 509 9.13k
2025-03-26 1.64k 10.6k 2 417 1.27k 533 9.15k
2025-03-27 1.71k 10.6k 2 450 1.35k 554 9.16k
2025-03-28 1.75k 10.8k 2 476 1.4k 558 9.22k
2025-03-29 1.79k 10.9k 2 494 1.45k 562 9.26k
2025-03-30 1.83k 11k 2 516 1.47k 562 9.27k
2025-03-31 1.87k 11.1k 2 537 1.52k 571 9.31k
2025-04-01 1.92k 11.2k 2 570 1.55k 572 9.33k
2025-04-02 1.9k 11.3k 2 581 1.59k 576 9.36k
2025-04-03 1.81k 11.3k 2 609 1.6k 580 9.39k
2025-04-04 1.78k 11.4k 2 612 1.61K 580 9.41k

Done.

610
 
 
611
 
 

PlaceSpeak is also B Corp Certified.

612
613
614
615
616
617
618
619
 
 
620
7
submitted 5 months ago by Sunshine to c/fairvote
 
 

From a political-philosophical perspective, referendums are an expression of direct democracy, but today, most referendums need to be understood within the context of representative democracy. They tend to be used quite selectively, covering issues such as changes in voting systems, where currently elected officials may not have the legitimacy or inclination to implement such changes.

621
 
 
622
 
 

Fair Vote Canada on Bluesky:

Tired of unaccountable "majority" governments elected with 40% of the vote?

The Ontario Green Party and Ontario NDP commit to proportional representation to make every vote count.

Nothing from the Ontario Liberal Party and Ontario PCs.

Read more:

https://www.fairvote.ca/22/02/2025/ontario-election-2025-where-parties-stand-on-proportional-representation/

Ontario Parties on Electoral Reform

Ontario PC: Nothing in platform. Ford is on record as opposed to electoral reform.

Ontario NDP: ✅Mixed Member Proportional Representation

Ontario Liberal: Nothing in platform. Bonnie Crombie previously said she would support a Citizens' Assembly.

Ontario Greens: ✅Proportional Representation ✅ Citizens' Assembly on Electoral Reform

623
16
Two party system (www.youtube.com)
submitted 5 months ago* (last edited 5 months ago) by Bublboi to c/fairvote
 
 

This is from Australia but it resonates here.

624
 
 
625
 
 

cross-posted from: https://lemmy.ca/post/39298754

I realize this community generally favours proportional representation, but I'm curious to hear your thoughts on a different approach to the problem of 'unrepresentative government'.

I question whether the goal of proportional representation, "every voter has 'their representative'", actually achieves what I consider to be a higher goal, "the government represents the interests of as many voters as possible".

If:

  • you have a perfectly 'proportionally representative' parliament
  • 51 of 100 of seats in said parliament are needed to form government
  • winning seats as a single party requires difficult campaigning
  • adding a party to a coalition requires difficult negotiation

Then anyone trying to grow a party or coalition with the goal of forming government will stop growing the coalition once they get 51 of 100 seats, because growing the coalition further requires difficult campaigning or negotiation, but yields no further benefit to the members of said coalition (since they would already have a majority at that point).

So even with PR, you still end up with a government that caters to a narrow majority and ignores social and economic problems that impact people outside that majority.

My solution, "a block of seats awarded in a nationwide winner-take-all Score Voting election," approaches this problem differently:

  • electing the ruling party directly,
  • and using Score Voting, where voters give each candidate a numerical score on an independent scale (note that Score Voting =/= Ranked Voting: a voter can give two different candidates the same score on the same ballot),
  • where a party can have 60% support and yet lose to a party with 70% support,
  • incentivizes candidate parties to try to exceed a 'mere majority' by as much as possible,
  • because a majority is no longer enough to guarantee a win,
  • because parties can no longer count on their own supporters exclusively supporting them.

I argue for Score Voting, but my rationale applies to Cardinal Voting systems in general.

TLDR: Score Voting is good.

Canadians want national unity.

The ideal of the Good Parliamentarian claims that politicians should, once elected, represent all their constituents and not just their core base, and that a governing party should, once elected, represent the nation as a whole, and not just their members.

So why is national unity a fleeting thing that emerges only in response to external threats, like American rhetoric about annexation and economic coercion, and why does it dissipate and devolve into factionalism once the threat is resolved (or when political campaigns simply drown the threat out)?

Because the Westminster System, in its present form, is institutionally biased towards division.

There are two reasons:

  1. Within individual constituencies, a narrow majority of voters is enough to guarantee a win, and
  2. In Parliament, a narrow majority of constituencies is enough to form government and pass law.

These have a common root cause:

Acquiring a narrow majority of something is the most efficient way to achieve the maximum reward.

If the easiest path to a win is to get the support of half-plus-one, who cares if you alienate everyone else on the other side?

The Solution: the Score Bonus System

This proposal suggests an incentive-based solution to create national unity:

The Score Bonus System: award a winner-take-all block of seats to the party that achieves the highest average score nationally in a Score Voting election.

Under this system, Canada's existing single-member districts are replaced with about half as many dual-member districts, each containing one 'constituency' seat and one 'national' seat.

In each district, candidates stand either as a 'constituency' candidate or as a 'national' candidate.

Voters mark their ballots by assigning numerical scores between 0 and 9 to each candidate, where higher scores indicate stronger approval.

Unlike ranking systems, this allows voters to express support for multiple candidates simultaneously.

Sample Ballot, Mapleford North, filled in by a sample voter

Seat Party Candidate Score (0 to 9)
Constituency Brown Party Jaclyn Hodges 5
Taupe Party Dexter Preston 0
Independent Cecelia Olson 9
Janice Fritz 5
National Brown Party Isreal Robles 7
Gale Sloan 8
Taupe Party Royce Brown 0
Beige Party Billie Burton 9

Each district's 'constituency' seat goes to the 'constituency' candidate with the highest average score in the district.

The collection of all districts' 'national' seats form the 'winner-take-all' block, which is awarded in full to the party with the highest nationwide score.

When a party has multiple candidates competing in the same constituency:

  • When computing nationwide averages, the score of its best candidate in each constituency is used.
  • If the party wins the highest nationwide average, its best candidates from each constituency win the 'national' seats.

However, if no party achieves a national average score of at least 50%, the 'national' seats instead go to the 'national' candidate with the highest average score in the constituency, effectively falling back to the 'constituency' method.

Seat Type Breakdown

Seat Type Seat Count Winning Candidate From Each Constituency
Constituency 172 (one per constituency) 'Constituency' candidate with highest score within constituency
National 172 (one per constituency) If any party has >50% approval nationwide: best 'national' candidate from party with highest score nationwide; otherwise: 'national' candidate with highest score within constituency
Total 344 (two per constituency)

Example Election Results

Constituency Results, Mapleford North

Seat Party Candidate C. Score N. Party Score
Constituency Brown Party J. Hodges 65% N/A
Taupe Party D. Preston 20% N/A
Independent C. Olson (Constituency Seat Winner) 80% N/A
J. Fritz 70% N/A
National Brown Party (Winning Party) I. Robles (Eliminated by G. Sloan) 65% 75%
G. Sloan (National Seat Winner) 75%
Taupe Party R. Brown 15% 55%
Beige Party B. Burton 80% 65%

National Results

Constituency Brown Party Score Taupe Party Score Beige Party Score
Mapleford North 75% 15% 80%
Rivermere South 70% 70% 20%
Ashbourne Springs 80% 55% 25%
...
National Average 75% (Winner) 55% 65%

Takeaways from example election results:

  • All three parties exceeded the 50% minimum average score threshold to be eligible for the 'national' seats.
  • C. Olson, an Independent, won the constituency seat for Mapleford North by having the highest average score (80%) of any candidate in the constituency. The next best constituency candidate was J. Fritz, a fellow Independent, who got an average score of 70%.
  • The Brown Party won all 172 national seats by having the highest national average score (75%) of any party in the nation. The next best national party was the Beige Party, which got a national average score of 65%.
  • The Brown Party ran two candidates in Mapleford North: I. Robles and G. Sloan. Of these candidates, G. Sloan had the higher score, of 75%, so I. Robles was eliminated and G. Sloan contributed his 75% constituency score to the party's national average.
  • G. Sloan was the surviving 'national' candidate nominated by the Brown Party in Mapleford North. Because the Brown Party won all national seats, G. Sloan won the 'national' seat for Mapleford North.
  • Candidates running for constituency seats do not affect the scores of national parties

Why This System?

Consider two things true for all elections:

  1. Winning votes is expensive.
  2. The candidate with the most votes wins.

If a voter can support only one candidate at a time, then the cheapest winning strategy for a candidate is to acquire a slim majority, to the exclusion of nearly half the voters. Any more would be wasteful; any less no longer guarantees a win.

If a voter can instead support many candidates at a time, then a narrow majority no longer guarantees a win: all of a candidate's supporters may also approve of a competitor. A candidate with 60% approval loses to a candidate with 70% approval. This forces candidates into a competition not for the exclusive support of a narrow majority, but for the approval of as many as possible.

The only way a minority group can be excluded under electoral systems with concurrent voter support is if the minority group is so fundamentally incompatible with a candidate's current base that adding the minority would cost them more members from their current base than the minority adds. If adding the minority would result in a net increase in voter support, a candidate must include them, or lose to a competitor who does, even if that candidate already has the support of a majority. Because that majority might be just as satisfied with the competitor.

Electing single representatives

First Past the Post and Instant Runoff voting both fall into the first category (voters support one candidate at a time). Instant Runoff is effectively a sequence of First Past the Post elections; in each round, voters support their top choice. A narrow majority under either system guarantees a win. Hence, Division.

Compare with Score Voting. Voters support many candidates concurrently. Hence, Unity.

Electing multiple representatives

Traditional constituency elections, regardless how votes are counted within each constituency, and Proportional Representation both suffer from the same exclusive-voter-support problem as FPTP and IRV: Each seat is awarded to one representative, so parties and coalitions compete for a narrow majority within the legislature.

While Proportional Representation ensures the makeup of the legislature is proportional to the makeup of the electorate as a whole, it fails to incentivize the ruling coalition to include more than half of said representatives, or by extension, more than half of the nation. Therefore, as long as a ruling coalition is confident in its majority, it will ignore social and economic problems that impact voters outside of said majority, even in Proportional Representation.

Instead, the Score Bonus System creates a nationwide single-winner election to effectively elect the ruling party as a whole, and using Score Voting for this election creates an incentive for this party to include the interests of as many as possible.

Electoral Systems Review

System Optimal strategy Effect
Single Seat FPTP Secure a narrow majority of votes. Division & Exclusion
Single Seat IRV Secure a narrow majority of votes. Division & Exclusion
Single Seat Score Appeal to as many voters as possible. Unity & Inclusion
Traditional Constituency Elections Secure a narrow majority of districts. Division & Exclusion
Proportional Representation Secure a narrow majority of voters. Division & Exclusion
Score Bonus System Appeal to as many voters as possible. Unity & Inclusion

Why combine the winner-take-all component with per-constituency elections?

Because:

  • It maintains a constituency-first element to politics, even in the winner-take-all segment of Parliament. The ruling party, with a majority given to it through the winner-take-all segment, has a representative from each constituency.
  • Allowing multiple candidates from the same party to run in the same constituency forces candidates to compete with fellow party members to best represent a constituency
  • Having some seats that are elected only by constituency voters ensures each constituency has a representative accountable only to them
  • The national seats only being awarded if a party gets >50% approval lets us fall back to conventional 'coalition government formation' with constituency-elected representatives if the winner-take-all election fails to produce a party with at least majority support. This avoids a party with, say, 35% nationwide approval, getting an automatic Parliamentary majority.
  • Having both constituency and national elections occur on the same ballot avoids unnecessary complexity for the voters. Voters get a single Score Voting ballot.The ballot is as complex as is required to implement Score Voting, but no more complicated than that.

What next

I realize we're not getting Score Voting in Canada any time soon. It's not well known enough, and the 'winner-take-all block of seats' component may scare people away.

Plus, no politician content with their party having an effective monopoly on opposing the other side would ever consider supporting an electoral system as competitive as this.

Instead, I offer this electoral system to anyone who wants to take advantage of an "oh won't somebody do something" vibe to organize something, but wants to avoid their organization getting burned by the faulty electoral systems we have today.

A protocol for building a unified chapter-based organization:

  1. Launch regional chapters
  2. Each regional chapter randomly selects N interested participants, plus one or two 'chapter founders', to act as delegates to meet in a central location or online. The first conference will bootstrap the organization's 'internal parties'. Subsequent conferences evolve into a recurring networking event.
  3. Like-minded delegates, possibly assisted by 'political speed-dating', form 'internal parties'
  4. In each chapter, 'internal parties' nominate candidates for chapter and national seats.
  5. Each member scores each candidate in their chapter
  6. The highest scored 'chapter seat' candidate in each chapter becomes the chapter's local representative
  7. The highest scored 'internal party' across the organization as a whole wins one 'national' representative in each chapter
  8. Canadians, Unite!

Thoughts?

view more: ‹ prev next ›